
NATIONAL JOBS FOR ALL COALITION
UNCOMMON
SENSE 20 © March 1998
REVERSING
THE SPREAD OF
LOUSY JOBS*
by
Chris Tilly, Professor of Regional Economic and Social Development,
University of Massachusetts at Lowell, and member of the editorial
collective, Dollars and Sense

Our economy
has expanded steadily, if unevenly, since the recession of 1990-91.
But how are we to evaluate such economic growth? Two important
questions to ask are these:
As we track the
economy from one boom to the next, does each successive boom leave
us better off than the one before?
Are we better off
today than our parents were at our age twenty-five or thirty years
ago? For the average American, the answer to both
questions is "no." How can we track the lost ground? There are
many different ways, but perhaps the most informative is a look
at the deteriorating quality of jobs.
Seven dimensions
of job quality
Twenty-five years
ago, we thought we knew the difference between good and bad jobs.
Good jobs were well-paid, secure, and connected to paths of upward
mobility. Bad jobs were low-paid, unstable, and dead-end. In the
optimism about economic growth of the postwar era, bad jobs were
peripheral and in the process of being swept away by economic
progress.
This picture of good
and bad jobs has been altered in three ways. First, people place
more value on issues such as autonomy and fulfillment on the job,
and on balancing work and family, reducing the dominance of bread
and butter issues such as wage levels. Second, the business press
and some scholars have challenged the notion that a good job is
a stable one, proposing instead that good jobs are stops--often
quite short ones--in an upward career trajectory. Third, and most
important, bad jobs can no longer be described as vestigial. They
form a central, and by many measures, growing portion of employment
in the United States.
No single measure
of job quality tells us all we want to know about jobs. So letôs
take a quick look at seven aspects of job quality: wages, fringe
benefits, due process in discipline, hours flexibility, permanence,
upward mobility, and control over the work process. If we go through
this checklist, the news is not exclusively bad, but it is so
overwhelmingly bad that it leaves little doubt that jobs are getting
worse.
Wages.
After controlling for inflation, workersô average hourly wage
fell by 13 percent between 1973 and 1996. This marks a dramatic
reversal: for every year between 1959 and 1973, the real wage
rose, during recession and expansion alike.1 Despite
the current expansion, average hourly pay is still not back to
its prerecession level. The declining average wage tells
only part of the bad news, because earnings inequality also increased
dramatically. The great irony is that this wage loss took place
at a time of increasing skill levels. Thus, an apparent paradox:
income gaps between workers with low and high levels of education
widened dramatically even as the workforce as a whole failed
to gain a payoff from its increased educational attainment and
skill. Minority workersô education increased as well: in
fact, blacks narrowed the education gap with whites, but experienced
a widening pay gap. For women workers, pay equity is still an
urgent issue, with nearly one-third of respondents to an AFL-CIO
survey reporting that their job does not pay equal wages for equal
work.2
Fringe benefits.
In response to alarm about falling real wages, some observers
argue that the wage is simply the wrong measure of pay. They point
out that although real (inflation-adjusted) wages fell while productivity
(output per worker) rose, real compensation has tracked productivity
much more closely. Compensation, which includes fringe benefits,
has been growing faster than wages.3 However,
including benefits is not as comforting as it first appears. For
one thing, US productivity growth (and therefore a major source
of compensation growth), lags behind that of other industrialized
countries. Even more troubling, the rise in the value of fringe
benefits over the last 20 years is driven primarily by the sharp
rise in the cost of health care. This generates another paradox:
though a growing share of compensation is devoted to health insurance,
a declining share of the working population is covered by employer-provided
health insurance, as well as other fringe benefits.
Due process.
Due process refers to protection from arbitrary punishment. Because
we think of due process as protection from government action,
we have largely surrendered the right to protection from arbitrary
action by employers--particularly regarding unfair firing. What
resources existed against unjust dismissal have largely evaporated.
Early laws restricting firing were overturned by court decisions
in the 19th century. Union coverage, which peaked at one-third
of the work force in the 1950s, provided an alternate source of
protection. But by 1996, the percentage of workers represented
by unions had dwindled to 16 percent (and only 11 percent in the
private sector),4 so union-enforced guarantees of due
process have become increasingly scarce.
From the 1970s onward,
there has been a growth of state-level case law barring "wrongful
discharge" by employers. While this might appear to take the place
of shrinking union protection, so far it has the character of
a lottery--yielding a few large settlements but no consistent
protection.
Hours flexibility.
People are primarily flexing to meet the demands of business,
not to please themselves. Adults are working more hours; in particular,
families are contributing more labor force hours, due to increased
paid work by women. As for the growth of "flexible" forms of employment,
this marks a decline rather than a rise in job quality, since
growing numbers of workers are stuck in part-time and temporary
work against their will. And they typically receive few benefits
and lower pay than others doing the same work.
Job permanence.
Are jobs becoming less permanent? Yes and no. Jobs are
becoming less permanent for men, particularly older men, and more
permanent for women. When these changes are combined, the net
effect is no detectable trend. However, this does not necessarily
imply that the changes are benign. Womenôs growing job tenure
probably results from the fact that women are now more likely
to choose to stay at jobs rather than quit. This may reflect their
greater attachment to the labor force, and not that there are
more permanent jobs. In fact, menôs declining job tenure tells
us that permanent jobs are becoming less available. Employers
are now more likely to lay off or fire workers or shut down.
Is the shortening
of job duration a bad thing? Some in the business press have argued
that frequent job changes facilitate ongoing learning and advancement,
and that rather than viewing shorter tenure as a setback, it should
simply be seen as a change in the patterns and rules of job-holding.
But one survey that asked workers to rate job quality found that
a 10 percent increase in the expected risk of job loss in the
next two years reduces their jobôs rating as much as a 10 percent
pay cut! And though the earnings penalty associated with changes
due to job loss was lower in the 1980s than in the 1970s, it remained
a penalty. While some fast-track workers are using more frequent
job changes to advance, most workers experience shorter-term employment
as a reduction in job satisfaction. Also, changing jobs often
means loss or reduction of benefits such as pension rights.
Mobility.
Closely related to the issue of permanence is the question of
mobility over time. Good jobs presumably offer upward mobility.
The fate of average wages, described earlier, does not necessarily
tell us about the earnings trajectories of individuals over time.
But in fact, the story is quite similar. Economy-wide, downward
mobility has become markedly more common. The possibilities of
upward mobility with a particular employer have contracted and
the opportunities for ascent via movement from job to job have
not offset this contraction.
Control over
the work process. Workers value control over the work
process highly. Perhaps the most compelling claim about recent
workplace changes is that they have indeed empowered workers.
How valid is this claim? Surveys show a rapid spread of reported
"high-performance" work practices, but these results are difficult
to interpret in terms of actual worker empowerment. We know from
case studies that some companies are actually expanding worker
control over the work process, but that many companies claiming
to embrace high-performance principles have not loosened managementôs
dictatorship.
Summing up,
jobs in the United States have definitely gotten worse over the
past two or three decades. Real wages have fallen, and fringe
benefits and due process have become less widely available. Small
advances in family-friendly schedule flexibility have been overwhelmed
by unwelcome schedule constraints imposed by employers. More frequent
job changes and a shift from within-company to between-company
mobility represent new opportunities for some, but translate into
less favorable wage trajectories for the average worker.
High-performance
work practices, finally, may hold the seeds of long-term improvements
in job quality, but they have not yet demonstrated that potential.
Indeed, it is not yet clear these seeds can take root as long
as other trends in job quality continue to undermine worker security
and commitment.
Why, and what
to do about it.
This deterioration
of job quality generally reflects the reduced power of workers
relative to employers. Three areas of economic change have contributed
this trend. The first is increased competition. Globalization
is one source of heightened competitiveness. Deregulation, accelerated
technological change, and the greater focus on short-term profits
by corporate mangers and shareholders all contribute to
this rise in competitiveness as well, opening new industries to
competition. The second major change is faster technological change
itself. Besides creating new areas of competition, for example,
a wide range of telecommunications media, technological change
has spurred worker displacement and job redefinition.
Underlying several
of these trends is a reality of the job market in the United States:
its chronic failure to provide jobs for all who want them, even
poor jobs. Studies have shown that even in the best of times,
there are several job seekers for every job. Despite its recent
fall, unemployment in recent decades has been extensive,5 and
an important source of weakened unions. And government itself
helped create an atmosphere in which union-busting became respectable.
Like the United States, the rest of the industrialized world
has experienced these changes in technology and increased global
competitiveness (and, to a lesser extent, other escalation in
competitive pressure). But despite significant stress on their
industrial systems, including higher unemployment rates, in no
other country have workers experienced the kind of collapse in
job quality and surge in inequality experienced by US workers.
Explaining this difference is the third factor: US businesses
have, for the most part, responded to new competitive pressures
by holding down wages rather by than enhancing quality. Their
political supporters have extended this logic to government, weakening
or dismantling many of the laws and regulations that protected
workers from the full force of market pressures. For example,
the value of the minimum wage was allowed to erode sharply, employers
have violated collective bargaining rights with impunity, and
sweatshops that operate under grossly unsafe conditions have proliferated.
To move away
from our current path and back toward good jobs, these changes
are particularly critical:
government
adoption of a full employment program which makes available a
job at decent pay to all who want one;
revitalization
of the labor movement, the agent most invested in pressing a good
job agenda;
strengthened
labor legislation and enforcement that ensure worker and union
rights;
promotion
of true high-performance work organization;
strengthened
provisions designed to protect those at a disadvantage in the
labor market, such as the minimum wage,6 gender pay equity, and
anti-discrimination laws;
a stronger,
broader safety net of social benefits;
increased
investment in training;
expanded work/family
flexibility;
reduced work hours,
and income guarantees tied to a wide range of socially productive
work.
Obviously, this agenda
does not correspond to current economic and political priorities.
Balanced budgets, tax cuts, and a devotion to the use of market-based
decision-making do not leave room for such initiatives. Federal
Reserve policy has mostly been to raise interest rates at every
sign of potential wage increases. Neither is pressing corporations
to improve conditions for their workers viewed as good market
practice. But union and non-union workers alike should ask their
elected officials what they plan to do to support this agenda.
Community-labor coalitions have begun to win city-level "living
wage" ordinances that set a minimum wage high enough to lift a
family of four out of official poverty, and we should be asking
our own municipality to adopt such a law. We need to join all
those who have lost income or economic security and elders, low-income
single mothers, artists, and others who face declines in badly-needed
government assistance in asking this society if it truly realizes
where its fascination with the economic law of the jungle is leading.
We should be asking our employers what they can do to create better
jobs--and forming unions to add clout to the question. We may
not have all the answers, but asking the right questions about
jobs in the US economy would be a big step in the right direction.
Notes:
1. One result is that US workers have fallen behind
those in other industrialized countries. Using a purchasing power
parity standard for currency conversion [converting currencies
based on the prices paid for a standard market basket of goods],
US hourly compensation in 1992 lagged behind that in Germany,
Belgium, and the Netherlands; US workers fell dead even with Italian
workers (Freeman 1994, Table 1.2).
2. "Women @Work," American @ Work, Sept.
1997, p. 14.
3. For example, Herbert Stein, "A Primer on
Pay and Productivity," Wall Street Journal, 8/23/1995 .
4. Union membership in 1996 was 14.5 percent (10
percent in the private sector).
5. See Uncommon Sense # 4: "Employment Statistics:
Letôs Tell the Whole Story."
6. See Uncommon Sense #10: "Letôs Have
an Adequate Minimum Wage."
______________
Editor: June Zaccone, Economics (Emer.), Hofstra University and
Helen Lachs Ginsburg, Economics (Emer.), Brooklyn College, CUNY |